Lawmakers Troll for Tolls


PUBLISHED: April 10, 2019

When Hartford, Conn.’s Charter Oak Bridge opened in 1942, local officials gave 13 year-old William Thornton the ceremonial privilege of paying the first toll to cross it. On April 28, 1989, Mr. Thornton paid the last state highway toll in Connecticut as he drove across the same bridge, marking the end of a lengthy battle over toll collections on the Connecticut Turnpike, Merritt Parkway and other state roads.

The argument against tolling was straightforward: Toll booths caused congestion and delays; idling cars wasted gas and spewed pollutants; and the enterprise of hiring and maintaining a staff of toll collectors was more trouble than it was worth. Police were also concerned about accidents as motorists jockeyed for position at toll plazas. So during the 1980s Connecticut did away with its toll system, culminating in Thornton’s final ride.

Now, because of digital technology, tolls are making a comeback. Connecticut lawmakers are considering the construction of more than 50 toll collection points across the state to raise billions of dollars. The old arguments no longer apply. These days tolls can be collected easily and efficiently using digital transponders coupled with receivers and high-speed cameras on highway gantries. Nationally, it's open season for dinging motorists.

In New York City, "congestion pricing" will require motorists to pay a fee of $10 or more to drive into Midtown Manhattan. The plan is expected to generate $1 billion annually. Other regressive highway fees are spreading rapidly. "Lexus Lanes" allow motorists who can afford it to whiz past those who can’t. The evolution of this form of highway robbery underscores government indifference toward the poor, as well as its fascination with digital tolling.

Initially, express lanes were known as High Occupancy Vehicle lanes, a reasonable effort by state and local governments to encourage carpooling. Over time, pollution-conscious officials expanded HOV lane access on some highways to single-occupant electric or hybrid vehicles.

Then greed and technology took over and many localities—primarily in zones near Los Angeles, San Francisco and Washington, D.C.—decided that express lanes would be open to anyone, whether they carpooled or not and regardless of the type of car they drove, if they simply paid a fee.

What had been a fair method of cutting highway congestion became one of the nation’s most regressive tax ploys, with some commuters paying $10 or more to travel in the fast lanes. This was impossible before the advent of EZ-Pass and similar collection systems.

As for congestion pricing, it has been implemented in several large European cities including London, reportedly reducing auto traffic by about 10% in the central business district. Los Angeles is considering a plan to charge motorists $4 to enter the city’s most trafficked area during rush hours.

Most of these programs come with admirable goals. Money collected from express lanes is usually used for highway repairs, and New York’s proposed congestion pricing would fund improvements to the dilapidated subway system.

But that doesn’t make the charges fair, or any less regressive. Too often in government the road to exploitation is paved with good intentions.

(c) Peter Funt. This column originally appeared in The Wall Street Journal.



Index of Previous Columns